Developments in 19th-century Europe are bounded by two great events. The French Revolution broke out in 1789, and its effects reverberated throughout much of Europe for many decades. World War I began in 1914. Its inception resulted from many trends in European society, culture, and diplomacy during the late 19th century. In between these boundaries—the one opening a new set of trends, the other bringing long-standing tensions to a head—much of modern Europe was defined.
Europe during this 125-year span
was both united and deeply divided. A number of basic cultural trends,
including new literary styles and the spread of science, ran through the entire
continent. European states were increasingly locked in diplomatic interaction,
culminating in continentwide alliance systems after 1871. At the same time,
this was a century of growing nationalism, in which individual states jealously
protected their identities and indeed established more rigorous border controls
than ever before. Finally, the European continent was to an extent divided between
two zones of differential development. Changes such as the Industrial
Revolution and political liberalization spread first and fastest in western
Europe—Britain, France, the Low Countries, Scandinavia, and, to an extent,
Germany and Italy. Eastern and southern Europe, more rural at the outset of the
period, changed more slowly and in somewhat different ways.
Europe witnessed important
common patterns and increasing interconnections, but these developments must be
assessed in terms of nation-state divisions and, even more, of larger regional
differences. Some trends, including the ongoing impact of the French
Revolution, ran through virtually the entire 19th century. Other
characteristics, however, had a shorter life span.
Some historians prefer to divide
19th-century history into relatively small chunks. Thus, 1789–1815 is defined
by the French Revolution and Napoleon; 1815–48 forms a period of reaction and
adjustment; 1848–71 is dominated by a new round of revolution and the
unifications of the German and Italian nations; and 1871–1914, an age of
imperialism, is shaped by new kinds of political debate and the pressures that
culminated in war. Overriding these important markers, however, a simpler
division can also be useful. Between 1789 and 1849 Europe dealt with the forces
of political revolution and the first impact of the Industrial Revolution.
Between 1849 and 1914 a fuller industrial society emerged, including new forms
of states and of diplomatic and military alignments. The mid-19th century, in either
formulation, looms as a particularly important point of transition within the
extended 19th century.
The Industrial Revolution
Economic effects
Undergirding the development of
modern Europe between the 1780s and 1849 was an unprecedented economic
transformation that embraced the first stages of the great Industrial
Revolution and a still more general expansion of commercial activity.
Articulate Europeans were initially more impressed by the screaming political
news generated by the French Revolution and ensuing Napoleonic Wars, but in
retrospect the economic upheaval, which related in any event to political and
diplomatic trends, has proved more fundamental.
Major economic change was spurred
by western Europe’s tremendous population
growth during the late 18th century, extending well into the 19th
century itself. Between 1750 and 1800, the populations of major countries
increased between 50 and 100 percent, chiefly as a result of the use of new
food crops (such as the potato) and a temporary decline in epidemic disease.
Population growth of this magnitude compelled change. Peasant and artisanal
children found their paths to inheritance blocked by sheer numbers and thus had
to seek new forms of paying labour. Families of businessmen and landlords also
had to innovate to take care of unexpectedly large surviving broods. These
pressures occurred in a society already attuned to market transactions,
possessed of an active merchant class, and blessed with considerable capital
and access to overseas markets as a result of existing dominance in world
trade.
Heightened commercialization
showed in a number of areas. Vigorous peasants increased their landholdings,
often at the expense of their less fortunate neighbours, who swelled the
growing ranks of the near-propertyless. These peasants, in turn, produced food
for sale in growing urban markets. Domestic
manufacturing soared, as hundreds of thousands of rural producers worked full-
or part-time to make thread and cloth, nails and tools under the sponsorship of
urban merchants. Craft work in the cities began to shift toward production for
distant markets, which encouraged artisan-owners to treat their journeymen less
as fellow workers and more as wage labourers. Europe’s social structure changed
toward a basic division, both rural and urban, between owners and nonowners.
Production expanded, leading by the end of the 18th century to a first wave of
consumerism as rural wage earners began to purchase new kinds of commercially
produced clothing, while urban middle-class families began to indulge in new
tastes, such as uplifting books and educational toys for children.
In this context an outright
industrial revolution took shape, led by Britain,
which retained leadership in industrialization
well past the middle of the 19th century. In 1840, British steam engines were
generating 620,000 horsepower out of a European total of 860,000. Nevertheless,
though delayed by the chaos of the French Revolution and Napoleonic Wars, many
western European nations soon followed suit; thus, by 1860 British
steam-generated horsepower made up less than half the European total, with
France, Germany, and Belgium gaining ground rapidly. Governments and private
entrepreneurs worked hard to imitate British technologies after 1820, by which
time an intense industrial revolution was taking shape in many parts of western
Europe, particularly in coal-rich regions such as Belgium, northern France, and
the Ruhr area of Germany. German pig iron production, a mere 40,000 tons in
1825, soared to 150,000 tons a decade later and reached 250,000 tons by the
early 1850s. French coal and iron output doubled in the same span—huge changes
in national capacities and the material bases of life.
Technological change soon
spilled over from manufacturing into other areas. Increased production
heightened demands on the transportation
system to move raw materials and finished products. Massive road and canal
building programs were one response, but steam
engines also were directly applied as a result of inventions in
Britain and the United States. Steam shipping plied major waterways soon after
1800 and by the 1840s spread to oceanic transport. Railroad
systems, first developed to haul coal from mines, were developed for intercity
transport during the 1820s; the first commercial line opened between Liverpool
and Manchester in 1830. During the 1830s local rail networks fanned out in most
western European countries, and national systems were planned in the following
decade, to be completed by about 1870. In communication, the invention of the
telegraph allowed faster exchange of news and commercial information than ever
before.
New organization of business
and labour
was intimately linked to the new technologies. Workers in the industrialized
sectors laboured in factories rather than in scattered shops or homes. Steam
and water power required a concentration of labour close to the power source.
Concentration of labour also allowed new discipline and specialization, which
increased productivity.
The new machinery was expensive,
and businessmen setting up even modest factories had to accumulate substantial
capital through partnerships, loans from banks, or joint-stock ventures. While
relatively small firms still predominated, and managerial bureaucracies were
limited save in a few heavy industrial giants, a tendency toward expansion of
the business unit was already noteworthy. Commerce was affected in similar
ways, for new forms had to be devised to dispose of growing levels of
production. Small shops replaced itinerant peddlers in villages and small
towns. In Paris, the department store,
introduced in the 1830s, ushered in an age of big business in the trading
sector.
Urbanization
was a vital result of growing commercialization and new industrial technology.
Factory centres such as Manchester grew from villages into cities of
hundreds of thousands in a few short decades. The percentage of the total
population located in cities expanded steadily, and big cities tended to
displace more scattered centres in western Europe’s urban map. Rapid city
growth produced new hardships, for housing stock and sanitary facilities could
not keep pace, though innovation responded, if slowly. Gas lighting improved
street conditions in the better neighborhoods from the 1830s onward, and
sanitary reformers pressed for underground sewage systems at about this time.
For the better-off, rapid suburban growth allowed some escape from the worst
urban miseries.
Rural life changed less
dramatically. A full-scale technological revolution in the countryside
occurred only after the 1850s. Nevertheless, factory-made tools spread widely
even before this time, as scythes replaced sickles for harvesting, allowing a
substantial improvement in productivity. Larger estates, particularly in
commercially minded Britain, began to introduce newer equipment, such as seed
drills for planting. Crop rotation, involving the use of nitrogen-fixing
plants, displaced the age-old practice of leaving some land fallow, while
better seeds and livestock and, from the 1830s, chemical fertilizers improved
yields as well. Rising agricultural production and market specialization were
central to the growth of cities and factories.
The speed of western Europe’s
Industrial Revolution should not be exaggerated. By 1850 in Britain, far and
away the leader still, only half the total population lived in cities, and
there were as many urban craft producers as there were factory hands.
Relatively traditional economic sectors, in other words, did not disappear and
even expanded in response to new needs for housing construction or food
production. Nevertheless, the new economic sectors grew most rapidly, and even
other branches displayed important new features as part of the general process
of commercialization.
Geographic disparities
complicate the picture as well. Belgium and, from the 1840s, many of the German
states were well launched on an industrial revolution that brought them
steadily closer to British levels. France, poorer in coal, concentrated
somewhat more on increasing production in craft sectors, converting furniture
making, for example, from an artistic endeavour to standardized output in advance
of outright factory forms. Scandinavia and the Netherlands joined the
industrial parade seriously only after 1850.
Southern and eastern Europe,
while importing a few model factories and setting up some local rail lines,
generally operated in a different economic orbit. City growth and technological
change were both modest until much later in the 19th century, save in pockets
of northern Italy and northern Spain. In eastern areas, western Europe’s
industrialization had its greatest impact in encouraging growing conversion to
market agriculture, as Russia, Poland, and Hungary responded to grain import
needs, particularly in the British Isles. As in eastern Prussia, the temptation
was to impose new obligations on peasant serfs labouring on large estates,
increasing the work requirements in order to meet export possibilities without
fundamental technical change and without challenging the hold of the landlord
class.
Summary
Although Western Europe had long had the basic
trappings of capitalism (private property, wealth accumulation, contracts), the
Industrial Revolution fueled the creation of a truly modern capitalist
system. Widespread credit, business corporations, investments and large-scale
stock markets all become common. Britain led the way in this transformation.
By the 1780s, the British Industrial Revolution,
which had been developing for several decades, began to further accelerate.
Manufacturing, business, and the number of wage laborers skyrocketed, starting
a trend that would continue into the first half of the 19th century. Meanwhile,
technology changed: hand tools were replaced by steam- or electricity-driven
machines.
The economic transformation brought about the
British industrial revolution was accompanied by a social transformation as
well. Population boomed, and demographics shifted. Because industrial resources
like coal and iron were in Central and Northern England, a shift in population
from Southern England northward took place. Northern cities like Manchester
grew tremendously. These changes in social and demographic realities created
vast pressure for political change as well. The first act to protect workers
went into affect in 1802 (though in practice it did very little). Pressure to
redress the lack of representation for the new industrial cities and the newly
wealthy industrial manufacturers also began to build.
Meanwhile, industrialists developed an ideology
called Laissez Faire based on Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations (1776) and
continued by David Ricardo and Robert Malthus. Based on this, the discipline
known as "economics" developed, largely to give the manufacturers a
basis for arguing for little or no regulation of industry. Instead of government
interference, these economists argued that a free market, in which everyone
followed their own self- interest, would maximize the nation's utility.
Britain, with its head start in manufacturing, its
many world markets, and its dominant navy, would dominate industry for most of
the 19th century. Towards the end of that century, the United States and
Germany would begin to challenge Britain's industrial power.
Commentary
Among the Western European countries, Britain was
the ideal incubator for the Industrial Revolution because an "Agricultural
Revolution" preceded it. After the 1688 "Glorious Revolution",
the British kings lost power and the aristocratic landholders gained power. The
landholders tried to rationalize their landholdings and started the Enclosure
Movement to bring more and more of their own land under tighter control, a
process that went on throughout the 1700s. This policy had two main effects: it
increased the productivity of the land, and transformed the people who used to
work land into an unemployed, labor class of poor in need of work. Thus, the
first factories had a ready labor- supply in Britain that was not available in
other nations. Important inventions like the "Spinning Jenny" to
produce yarn began to be made in 1760s, and soon the British textile industry
was booming, aided by Eli Whitney's invention of the "Cotton Gin" in
America, which provided a ready source of cotton.
Most products people in the industrialized nations use today are turned
out swiftly by the process of mass production, by people (and sometimes,
robots) working on assembly lines using power-driven machines. People of
ancient and medieval times had no such products. They had to spend long,
tedious hours of hand labor even on simple objects. The energy, or power, they
employed in work came almost wholly from their own and animals' muscles. The
Industrial Revolution is the name given the movement in which machines changed
people's way of life as well as their methods of manufacture.
About the time of the American Revolution, the people of England began to
use machines to make cloth and steam engines to run the machines. A little
later they invented locomotives. Productivity began a spectacular climb. By
1850 most Englishmen were laboring in industrial towns and Great Britain had
become the workshop of the world. From Britain the Industrial Revolution spread
gradually throughout Europe and to the United States.
Changes That Led to the Revolution
The most important of the changes that brought about the Industrial Revolution
were (1) the invention of machines to do the work of hand tools; (2) the use of
steam, and later of other kinds of power, in place of the muscles of human
beings and of animals; and (3) the adoption of the factory system.
It is almost impossible to imagine what the world would be like if the
effects of the Industrial Revolution were swept away. Electric lights would go
out. Automobiles and airplanes would vanish. Telephones, radios, and television
would disappear Most of the abundant stocks on the shelves of department stores
would be gone. The children of the poor would have little or no schooling and
would work from dawn to dark on the farm or in the home. Before machines were
invented, work by children as well as by adults was needed in order to provide
enough food, clothing, and shelter for all.
The Industrial Revolution came gradually. It happened in a short span of
time, however, when measured against the centuries people had worked entirely
by hand. Until John Kay invented the flying shuttle in 1733 and James
Hargreaves the spinning jenny 31 years later, the making of yarn and the
weaving of cloth had been much the same for thousands of years. By 1800 a host
of new and faster processes were in use in both manufacture and transportation.
This relatively sudden change in the way people live deserves to be
called a revolution. It differs from a political revolution in its greater
effects on the lives of people and in not coming to an end, as, for example,
did the French Revolution.
Instead, the Industrial Revolution grew more powerful each year as new
inventions and manufacturing processes added to the efficiency of machines and
increased productivity. Indeed, since World War I the mechanization of industry
has increased so enormously that another revolution in production is taking
place
Expanding Commerce Affects Industry
Commerce and industry have always been closely related. Sometimes one is
ahead and sometimes the other, but the one behind is always trying to catch up.
Beginning in about 1400, world commerce grew and changed so greatly that
writers sometimes use the term "commercial revolution" to describe
the economic progress of the next three and a half centuries.
Many factors helped bring about this revolution in trade. The Crusades
opened up the riches of the East to Western Europe. America was discovered, and
European nations began to acquire rich colonies there and elsewhere. New trade
routes were opened. The strong central governments which replaced the feudal
system began to protect and help their merchants. Trading firms, such as the
British East India Company, were chartered by governments. Larger ships were
built, and flourishing cities grew up.
With the expansion of trade, more money was needed. Large-scale commerce
could not be carried on by barter, as much of the earlier trade had been. Gold
and silver from the New World helped meet this need. Banks and credit systems
developed. By the end of the 17th century Europe had a large accumulation of
capital. Money had to be available before machinery and steam engines could
come into wide use for they were costly to manufacture and install.
By 1750 large quantities of goods were being exchanged among the European
nations, and there was a demand for more goods than were being produced.
England was the leading commercial nation, and the manufacture of cloth was its
leading industry.
Organizing Production
Several systems of making goods had grown up by the time of the
Industrial Revolution. In country districts families produced most of the food,
clothing, and other articles they used, as they had done for centuries. In the
cities merchandise was made in shops much like those of the medieval craftsmen,
and manufacturing was strictly regulated by the guilds and by the government.
The goods made in these shops, though of high quality, were limited and costly.
The merchants needed cheaper items, as well as larger quantities, for
their growing trade. As early as the 15th century they already had begun to go
outside the cities, beyond the reach of the hampering regulations, and to
establish another system of producing goods.
From Cottage Industry to Factory
Cloth merchants, for instance, would buy raw wool from the sheep owners,
have it spun into yarn by farmers' wives, and take it to country weavers to be
made into textiles. These country weavers could manufacture the cloth more
cheaply than city craftsmen could because they got part of their living from
their gardens or small farms.
The merchants would then collect the cloth and give it out again to
finishers and dyers. Thus they controlled clothmaking from start to finish.
Similar methods of organizing and controlling the process of manufacture came
to prevail in other industries, such as the nail, cutlery, and leather goods.
Some writers call this the putting-out system. Others call it the
domestic system because the work was done in the home ("domestic"
comes from the Latin word for home). Another term is cottage industry, for most
of the workers belonged to the class of farm laborers known as cotters and
carried on the work in their cottages.
This system of industry had several advantages over older systems. It
gave the merchant a large supply of manufactured articles at a low price. It
also enabled him to order the particular kinds of items that he needed for his
markets. It provided employment for every member of a craft worker's family and
gave jobs to skilled workers who had no capital to start businesses for
themselves. A few merchants who had enough capital had gone a step further.
They brought workers together under one roof and supplied them with spinning
wheels and looms or with the implements of other trades. These establishments
were factories, though they bear slight resemblance to the factories of today.
Why the Revolution Began in England
English merchants were leaders in developing a commerce which increased
the demand for more goods. The expansion in trade had made it possible to
accumulate capital to use in industry. A cheaper system of production had grown
up which was largely free from regulation.
There also were new ideas in England which aided the movement. One of
these was the growing interest in scientific investigation and invention.
Another was the doctrine of laissez-faire, or letting business alone. This
doctrine had been growing in favor throughout the 18th century. It was
especially popular after the British economist Adam Smith argued powerfully for
it in his great work 'The Wealth of Nations' (1776).
For centuries the craft guilds and the government had controlled commerce
and industry down to the smallest detail. Now many Englishmen had come to
believe that it was better to let business be regulated by the free play of
supply and demand rather than by laws. Thus the English government for the most
part kept its hands off and left business free to adopt the new inventions and
the methods of production which were best suited to them.
The most important of the machines that ushered in the Industrial
Revolution were invented in the last third of the 18th century. Earlier in the
century, however, three inventions had been made which opened the way for the
later machines. One was the crude, slow-moving steam engine built by Thomas
Newcomen (1705), which was used to pump water out of mines. The second was John
Kay's flying shuttle (1733). It enabled one person to handle a wide loom more
rapidly than two persons could operate it before. The third was a frame for
spinning cotton thread with rollers, first set up by Lewis Paul and John Wyatt
(1741). Their invention was not commercially practical, but it was the first
step toward solving the problem of machine spinning.
Inventions in Textile Industry
As the flying shuttle sped up weaving, the demand for cotton yarn
increased. Many inventors set to work to improve the spinning wheel. James
Hargreaves, a weaver who was also a carpenter, patented his spinning jenny in
1770. It enabled one worker to run eight spindles instead of one.
About the same time Richard Arkwright developed his water frame, a
machine for spinning with rollers operated by water power. In 1779 Samuel
Crompton, a spinner, combined Hargreaves' jenny and Arkwright's roller frame
into a spinning machine, called a mule. It produced thread of greater fineness
and strength than the jenny or the roller frame. Since the roller frame and the
mule were large and heavy, it became the practice to install them in mills,
where they could be run by water power. They were tended by women and children.
These improvements in spinning machinery called for further improvements
in weaving. In 1785 Edmund Cartwright patented a power loom. In spite of the
need for it, weaving machinery came into use very slowly. First, many
improvements had to be made before the loom was satisfactory. Second, the hand
weavers violently opposed its adoption because it threw many of them out of
work. Those who got jobs in the factories were obliged to take the same pay as
unskilled workers. Thus they rioted, smashed the machines, and tried to prevent
their use. The power loom was only coming into wide operation in the cotton
industry by 1813. It did not completely replace the hand loom in weaving cotton
until 1850. It was not well adapted to the making of some woolens. As late as
1880 many hand looms were still in use for weaving woolen cloth.
Many other machines contributed to the progress of the textile industry.
In 1785 Thomas Bell of Glasgow invented cylinder printing of cotton goods. This
was a great improvement on block printing. It made successive impressions of a
design "join up" and did the work more rapidly and more cheaply. In
1793 the available supply of cotton was increased by Eli Whitney's invention of
the cotton gin. In 1804 J.M. Jacquard, a Frenchman, perfected a loom on which
patterns might be woven in fabrics by mechanical means. This loom was later
adapted to the making of lace, which became available to everyone
Watt's Steam Engine
While textile machinery was developing, progress was being made in other
directions. In 1763 James Watt, a Scottish mechanic, was asked to repair a
model of a Newcomen steam engine. He saw how crude and inefficient it was and
by a series of improvements made it a practical device for running machinery.
Wheels turned by running water had been the chief source of power for the
early factories. These were necessarily situated on swift-running streams. When
the steam engine became efficient, it was possible to locate factories in more
convenient places.
Coal and Iron
The first users of steam engines were the coal and iron industries. They
were destined to be basic industries in the new age of machinery. As early as
1720 many steam engines were in operation. In coal mines they pumped out the
water which usually flooded the deep shafts. In the iron industry they pumped
water to create the draft in blast furnaces.
The iron industry benefited also from other early inventions of the 18th
century. Iron was scarce and costly, and production was falling off because
England's forests could not supply enough charcoal for smelting the ore.
Ironmasters had long been experimenting with coal as a fuel for smelting.
Finally the Darby family, after three generations of effort, succeeded with
coal that had been transformed into coke. This created a new demand for coal
and laid the foundation for the British coal industry. The next great steps
were taken in the 1780s, when Henry Cort developed the processes of puddling
and rolling. Puddling produced nearly pure malleable iron. Hand in hand with
the adoption of the new inventions went the rapid development of the factory
system of manufacture.
Changing Conditions in England
The new methods increased the amount of goods produced and decreased the
cost. The worker at a machine with 100 spindles on it could spin 100 threads of
cotton more rapidly than 100 workers could on the old spinning wheels. Southern
planters in the United States were able to meet the increased demand for raw
cotton because they were using the cotton gin. This machine could do the job of
50 men in cleaning cotton. Similar improvements were being made in other lines
of industry. British merchants no longer found it a problem to obtain enough
goods to supply their markets. On the contrary, at times the markets were
glutted with more goods than could be sold. Then mills were closed and workers
were thrown out of employment.
With English factories calling for supplies, such as American cotton, and
sending goods to all parts of the world, better transportation was needed. The
roads of England were wretchedly poor and often impassable. Packhorses and
wagons crawled along them, carrying small loads. Such slow and inadequate
transportation kept the cost of goods high. Here again the need produced the invention.
Thomas Telford and John MacAdam each developed a method of road construction
better than any that had been known since the ancient Romans built their famous
roads.
Building Canals and Railways
Many canals were dug. They connected the main rivers and so furnished a
network of waterways for transporting coal and other heavy goods. A canalboat
held much more than a wagon. It moved smoothly if slowly over the water, with a
single horse hitched to the towline. In some places, where it was impossible to
dig canals and where heavy loads of coal had to be hauled, mine owners laid
down wooden or iron rails. On these early railroads one horse could haul as
much coal as 20 horses could on ordinary roads.
Early in the 19th century came George Stephenson's locomotive and Robert
Fulton's steamboat, an American invention. They marked the beginning of modern
transportation on land and sea. Railroads called for the production of more
goods, for they put factory-made products within reach of many more people at
prices they could afford to pay.
The Condition of Labor
As conditions in industry changed, social and political conditions
changed with them. Farm laborers and artisans flocked to the manufacturing
centers and became industrial workers. Cities grew rapidly, and the percentage
of farmers in the total population declined.
The population of England as a whole began to increase rapidly after the
middle of the 18th century. Because of progress in medical knowledge and
sanitation, fewer people died in infancy or childhood and the average length of
life increased.
Far-reaching changes were gradually brought about in the life of the
industrial workers. For one thing, machines took a great burden of hard work
from the muscles of human beings. Some of the other changes, however, were not
so welcome.
The change from domestic industry to the factory system meant a loss of
independence to the worker. The home laborer could work whenever he pleased.
Although the need for money often drove him to toil long hours, he could vary
the monotony of his task by digging or planting his garden patch. When he
became a factory employee, he not only had to work long hours, but he had to
leave his little farm. He lived near the factory, often in a crowded slum district.
He was forced to work continuously at the pace set by the machine. The long
hours and the monotonous toil were an especially great hardship for the women
and children. The vast majority of the jobs were held by them by 1816.
The change was particularly hard on the weavers and the other skilled
workers who sank to the position of factory workers. They had been independent
masters, capitalists in a small way, and managers of their own businesses. They
had pride in their skill. When they saw themselves being forced into factories
to do other men's bidding for the same pay as unskilled workers, it is no
wonder that they rioted and broke up looms.
Problems of Capital and Labor
A person had to have a lot of capital to buy machines and open a factory.
Those who were successful made huge profits with which to buy more machines,
put up larger buildings, and purchase supplies in greater quantities at
enormous savings. Thus capital increased far more rapidly than it ever had
before. Much of it was invested in building canals, railroads, and steamships
and in developing foreign trade. The men who controlled these enterprises
formed a powerful new class in England--the industrial capitalists.
The capitalists had a struggle to obtain a voice in the government. They
needed a better system of banking, currency, and credit. They had to find and
hold markets for their products. They had many difficulties in organizing their
factories to run efficiently. They also had to make a profit on their
investments in the face of intense competition.
Laissez-faire was the rule in England. This meant that the government had
accepted the doctrine that it should keep hands off business. Factory owners
could therefore arrange working conditions in whatever way they pleased. Grave
problems arose for the workers--problems of working hours, wages, unemployment,
accidents, employment of women and children, and housing conditions.
Children could tend most of the machines as well as older persons could,
and they could be hired for less pay. Great numbers of them were worked form 12
to 14 hours a day under terrible conditions. Many were apprenticed to the
factory owners and housed in miserable dormitories. Ill-fed and ill-clothed,
they were sometimes driven under the lash of the overseer. The high death rate
of these child slaves eventually roused Parliament to pass laws limiting the
daily toil for apprentices.
Rise of Labor Unions
Workers sought to win improved conditions and wages through labor unions.
These unions often started as "friendly societies" that collected
dues from workers and extended aid during illness or unemployment. Soon,
however, they became organizations for winning improvements by collective
bargaining and strikes.
Industrial workers also sought to benefit themselves by political action.
They fought such legislation as the English laws of 1799 and 1800 forbidding
labor organizations. They campaigned to secure laws which would help them. The
struggle by workers to win the right to vote and to extend their political
power was one of the major factors in the spread of democracy during the 19th
century.
Revolution Spreads to the United States
Until 1815 France was busy with the Napoleonic wars. It had little
opportunity to introduce machinery. When peace came France began to follow England.
It followed slowly, however, and has never devoted itself as exclusively to
manufacturing as England has. Belgium was ahead of France in adopting the new
methods. The other European countries made little progress until the second
half of the 19th century.
The United States too was slow in adopting machine methods of
manufacture. Farming and trading were its chief interests until the Civil War.
The new nation had little capital with which to buy the machinery and put up
the buildings required. Such capital as existed was largely invested in
shipping and commerce. Labor was scarce because men continued to push westward,
clearing the forests and establishing themselves on the land.
A start in manufacturing, however, was made in New England in 1790 by Samuel
Slater. An employee of Arkwright's spinning mills, Slater came to the United
States in 1789. He was hired by Moses Brown of Providence, R. I., to build a
mill on the Pawtucket, or Seekonk, River. English laws forbade export of either
the new machinery or plans for making it. Slater designed the machine from
memory and built a mill which started operation in 1790. When the Napoleonic
wars and the War of 1812 upset commerce and made English products difficult to
obtain, more American investors began to build factories.
Pioneer Industries and Inventions
New England soon developed an important textile industry. It had swift
streams for power and a humid climate, which kept cotton and wool fibers in
condition for spinning and weaving. In Pennsylvania iron for machines, tools,
and guns was smelted in stone furnaces. They burned charcoal, plentiful in this
forested land. Spinning machines driven by steam were operating in New York by
1810. The first practical power loom was installed at Waltham, Mass., by Francis
Cabot Lowell in 1814. Shoemaking was organized into a factory system of
production in Massachusetts in the early 19th century. New England was the
first area in the United States to industrialize.
American inventors produced many new machines that could be applied to
industry as well as to agriculture. Oliver Evans designed a steam engine more
powerful than that of James Watt. Engineers quickly adopted the new engine and
used it to power locomotives and steamboats.
Cyrus McCormick invented several machines used to mechanize farming. His
mechanical reaper, patented in 1834, revolutionized harvesting, making it
quicker and easier. Elias Howe's sewing machine eased the life of the housewife
and made the manufacture of clothing less expensive.
Techniques of factory production were refined in American workshops. Eli
Whitney led the movement to standardize parts used in manufacture. They became
interchangeable, enabling unskilled workers to assemble products from boxes of
parts quickly. American factories used machine tools to make parts. These
machines were arranged in lines for more efficient production. This was called
the "American system of manufacturing," and it was admired by all
other industrial nations. It was first applied to the manufacture of firearms
and later spread to other industries like clock and lock making.
Second Industrial Revolution
The machines of the Industrial Revolution in the 18th and early 19th
centuries were simple, mechanical devices compared with the industrial
technology that followed. Many new products were devised, and important
advances were made in the system of mass production. Changes in industry were
so great that the period after 1860 has been called the Second Industrial
Revolution. New scientific knowledge was applied to industry as scientists and
engineers unlocked the secrets of physics and chemistry. Great new industries
were founded on this scientific advance: steel, chemicals, and petroleum
benefited from new understandings of chemistry; breakthroughs in the study of electricity
and magnetism provided the basis for a large electrical industry. These new
industries were larger and more productive than any industries existing before.
Germany and the United States became the leaders, and by the end of the 19th
century they were challenging Great Britain in the world market for industrial
goods.
The age of electricity began in 1882 when Thomas A. Edison introduced a
system of electric lighting in New York City. Electricity was later applied to
driving all kinds of machinery as well as powering locomotives and streetcars.
Electric lighting quickly spread across the United States and was soon adopted
in Europe. The electrical industry was dominated by large companies that
developed new products and then manufactured and marketed them. These companies
were based in Germany and the United States but sold their goods all over the
world. They were the first multinational companies. Companies like Westinghouse
and General Electric helped to electrify cities in Europe, Africa, and South
America.
The steel and chemical industries used new technology that greatly
increased production. The size of factories increased rapidly, employing more
workers and using more machinery. These industries integrated all stages of
production under a single corporate structure. They bought out competitors and
acquired sources of raw materials and retail outlets. Corporations such as U.S.
Steel and Standard Oil controlled all stages of manufacturing the product, from
mining and drilling to delivering it to the customer. This gave them great
economic power, and the United States government took measures to limit their
monopolies in steel and petroleum.
The larger size of business presented great challenges to managers who
administered enormous organizations with many branches and subsidiaries.
Advances in communications and transportation helped decision makers to
maintain control. The electric telegraph was invented by Samuel Morse in 1844
and was used to relay commercial information about prices and markets. It was
used in the stock exchanges and on the railway systems. Alexander Graham Bell
patented his telephone in 1876, and networks of telephone lines were built
quickly across the United States.
The telephone became a useful tool for managers to keep in contact with
the widely dispersed parts of their businesses. New methods of management were
devised that stressed central control, planning, and efficient production
methods. One of the leading advocates of "scientific management" was
Frederick Winslow Taylor.
The Second Industrial Revolution marked great progress in the methods of
mass production. More and more industries used interchangeable parts and
machine tools. Electric power replaced steam power in factories; it was
cheaper, faster, and more flexible. It allowed machine tools to be arranged
more efficiently. Human power was replaced by machine power. In 1913 Henry Ford
introduced the assembly line in the manufacture of his Model T Ford. Parts were
assembled on a moving conveyor belt, and the Model T took shape as it moved
from one work station to the next. The assembly line greatly increased the
speed of manufacture and soon was used in many industries.
By the outbreak of World War I in 1914, only a small number of industries
in the most industrialized nations of the world had adopted advanced production
methods and organization. Much of the world had not yet begun a first
industrial revolution. Russia, Canada, Italy, and Japan were just beginning to
industrialize.
Only Great Britain, the United States, Germany, France, and some parts of
the Scandinavian countries had successfully completed an industrial revolution.
Most of the world's population still worked in primitive agricultural
economies. China, India, and Spain did not begin to industrialize until well
into the 20th century.
Revolution and the growth of industrial society, 1789–1914
Reviewed by Spencer Reports
on
12:26 am
Rating:
No comments: